Skip to main content

A dynamic factor model for the Mexican economy: are common trends useful when predicting economic activity?

Abstract

In this paper we propose to use the common trends of the Mexican economy in order to predict economic activity one and two steps ahead. We exploit the cointegration properties of the macroeconomic time series, such that, when the series are I(1) and cointegrated, there is a factor representation, where the common factors are the common trends of the macroeconomic variables. Thus, we estimate a large non-stationary dynamic factor model using principal components (PC) as suggested by Bai (J Econom 122(1):137–183, 2004), where the estimated common factors are used in a factor-augmented vector autoregressive model to forecast the Global Index of Economic Activity. Additionally, we estimate the common trends through partial least squares. The results indicate that the common trends are useful to predict Mexican economic activity, and reduce the forecast error with respect to benchmark models, mainly when estimated using PC.

1 Introduction

In recent years, due to the availability of data on a vast number of correlated macroeconomic and financial variables collected regularly by statistical agencies, there has been an increasing interest in modeling large systems of economic time series. Therefore, econometricians have to deal with datasets consisting of hundreds of series, thus making the use of large dimensional dynamic factor models (DFMs) more attractive than the usual vector autoregressive (VAR) models, which usually limit the number of variables; see Boivin and Ng (2006). DFMs were introduced by Geweke (1977) and Sargent and Sims (1977) with the aim of representing the dynamics of large systems of time series through a small number of hidden common factors, and are mainly used for one of the following two objectives: first, forecasting macroeconomic variables and second, estimating the underlying factor in order to carry out policy-making (e.g., the business cycle; lagging, coincident, and leading indicators; or impulse-response functions, among other aspects). Another interesting application is to use the common factors as instrumental variables or exogenous regressors in panel data analysis. See Bai and Ng (2008), Stock and Watson (2011), and Breitung and Choi (2013) for a review of existing literature and applications of DFMs.

Note that macroeconomic time series are generally non-stationary and frequently cointegrated; see, for example, Kunst and Neusser (1997). On the other hand, a cointegrated system can be expressed in terms of a factor representation; see Stock and Watson (1988), Vahid and Engle (1993), Gonzalo and Granger (1995). Furthermore, these authors show that the common factor representation implies that the variables of the system are cointegrated if the common factors are I(1) and the individual effects are I(0). However, in practice, the cointegration results are not frequently used to predict macroeconomic variables, given that we differentiate each element of the factor representation individually.

Empirically, it is interesting to determine the number of common factors of the economy, given that we can summarize a large number of macroeconomic variables in few common trends.Footnote 1 Furthermore, by estimating the common factors we can observe the orthogonal dynamics of the economy, which is very important for macroeconomic policy. These common factors, for example, may be related to specific groups of variables, and it is interesting to analyze mechanisms of transmission to other groups of variables. Additionally, we can estimate the confidence intervals for the loading weights, common factors, and common components, which allow us to carry out statistical inference in order to better understand economic phenomena.

The stochastic common trends represent the long-run behavior of the variables. Previous studies related to this paper are Duy and Thoma (1998), who evaluate the improvement of the cointegration relationship in VAR models; Eickmeier and Ziegler (2008), who examine the use of the factor-augmented vector autoregressive (FAVAR) in order to predict macroeconomic and financial variables, focusing on the US economy. They conclude that on average, factor forecasts are slightly better than other models. Banerjee et al. (2014) incorporate the error correction term in FAVAR models, showing that their approach generally offers higher forecasting accuracy relative to the FAVAR. Also, Eickmeier et al. (2014) prove different specifications of FAVAR models, using time-varying coefficients (tv) and stochastic volatility errors. The main conclusion is that the FAVAR models, regardless of the specification, outperform univariate models on in-sample forecasts. When they evaluate the out-sample performance, there is no improvement with respect to the benchmark model. More recently, Hindrayanto et al. (2016) study the forecasting performance of a four factor model approach for large datasets. They conclude that a collapsed DFM is the most accurate model. Finally, Wilms and Croux (2016) propose a sparse cointegration method for a large set of variables by setting some coefficients in the cointegration relationship at exactly zero. They conclude that their method leads to significant forecast accuracy with respect to the method proposed by Johansen (1988, 1991). Other samples of reference are Stock and Watson (2002a, b), Marcellino et al. (2003), Peña and Poncela (2004), Reijer (2005), Schumacher (2007), Giannone et al. (2008), Eickmeier et al. (2014), Lahiri et al. (2015), and Panopoulou and Vrontos (2015), who show that DFMs are useful in order to reduce the forecast errors with respect to the traditional models, as autoregressive approaches and linear regressions with macroeconomic diffusion indexes.Footnote 2 It is important to comment that, in a similar way as we have proposed in this study but in a stationary framework, Bräuning and Koopman (2014) propose to use collapsed dynamic factor analysis in order to predict target variables of the economy, exploiting the state-space representation between the target variables and the common factors. They conclude that the forecast accuracy is improved with respect to benchmark models.

However, most empirical applications have been carried out for the US or Euro economies. Therefore, we propose a FAVAR model to predict Mexican economic activity using concepts of cointegration such that we forecast I(1) time series where the estimated common factors are the common trends of the economy. We readily exploit the long-run relationship between the common factors and the specific variable that we wish to predict.Footnote 3

We contribute to the literature in two ways: (1) empirically in determining the number of common trends of the Mexican economy and (2) the use of the common trends in order to predict economic activity. This is an advantage with respect to other alternatives, given that the FAVAR with cointegrated variables is very straightforward to implement computationally. Furthermore, we also direct our attention to the predictive capacity of macroeconomic variables and their common trends. In this way, we use the traditional method of principal components (PC) and additionally, partial least squares (PLS).

The rest of this paper is structured as follows. In Sect. 2, we summarize the historical behavior of the Mexican economy. In Sect. 3, we briefly explain the DFM and the FAVAR representation. In Sect. 4, we describe the estimation methods used. In Sect. 5, we describe the data, present the cointegration results, their descriptive predictive features, the empirical strategy to obtain small forecast errors, and the results obtained. Finally, we conclude in Sect. 6.

2 The Mexican economy

Mexico is one of the world’s leading emerging countries. According to data from the International Monetary Fund (IMF), it is the 11th largest economy and the largest emerging country outside the BRICs, i.e., Brazil, Russia, India, and China (Rodriguez-Pose and Villarreal 2015). In 2015, Mexico’s population ascended to 119.9 million and its GDP per capita stood at 9005.0 US dollars (World Bank 2016b).

After a prolonged period of sustained economic growth, the country began decelerating in the late 1970s. Following a sovereign default, Mexico encountered a severe economic crisis from 1982 to 1985. Subsequently, the Mexican government put forward a series of market reforms that culminated with the implementation of the North American Free Trade Agreement in 1994. These reforms included the privatization of previously government-operated firms, fiscal reforms, and opening the country to trade and foreign direct investment (FDI), among other actions (Kehoe and Ruhl 2010). Mexico’s economic transformation was successful in reducing inflation, maintaining fiscal discipline, reducing its external debt burden, and increasing trade as a share of GDP (Hanson 2010). Nonetheless, this was not accompanied by high levels of economic growth, as between 1982 and 2015 the country’s GDP grew at an average annual rate of 2.3% (World Bank 2016a).

Moreover, in recent decades the Mexican economy has regressed on different fronts. In 1995, Mexico was responsible for 7.0% of trade among economies classified by the IMF as emerging and developing, behind China at 12.7%. By 2008, China’s share was still the largest and totaled 22.3%, while Mexico dropped to third at 5.4%, behind Russia. Additionally, in 1995, China was the largest recipient of FDI to emerging and developing economies, accounting for 33.4%, while Mexico was second, receiving 8.5%. By 2008, Mexico’s position had weakened considerably, falling to seventh at 3.2% (Kehoe and Ruhl 2010). Factors, such as rigidities in the labor market, an inefficient financial sector, and a lack of contract enforcement, have limited Mexico’s capacity to benefit from its reforms and therefore hindered the country’s economic growth (Kehoe and Ruhl 2010).

As an economy open to world markets, Mexico hosts many modern firms, notably in the automobile, aerospace, and foods and beverages sectors, which employ highly skilled, well-educated, and well-remunerated workers. Nonetheless, this represents only a small part of the economy and is concentrated in a few regions of the country. Another segment of the economy is characterized by high levels of informality, low-skilled work, low productivity levels, and out-of-date technologies. Unregistered firms in the informal sector employ close to half of Mexico’s labor force, with workers that frequently lack access to a good education, reliable health care, and affordable financial services, conditions that strongly hamper their accumulation of human capital. Lastly, a third segment of the economy is made up of companies that, for long periods, have been protected from competition, particularly dominant firms in the energy and telecommunications sectors (Dougherty 2015).

During the global economic crisis of 2008–2009, Mexico’s GDP suffered a significant contraction, which was accentuated by a reduction in the amount of remittances the country receives from migrant workers based in the US and the outbreak of influenza A(H1N1) throughout the country. Nevertheless, due to an upgraded macroeconomic policy framework and careful regulation of the financial system, Mexico did not suffer the type of financial and fiscal crises experienced in other countries (Schwellnus 2011).

In the years following the global economic crisis, the Mexican economy was characterized by a persistent trend of increasing debt-to-GDP, which grew from 29.0% in 2007 to 50.5% in 2016, and a significant decline in the volume of oil production (World Bank 2016a). Output volatility in Mexico remained high, which can have high costs for individuals and for long-term growth. Furthermore, in Mexico, temporary disturbances in output are usually accompanied by temporary reductions in consumption, since a substantial share of the population is credit-constrained and the social safety net is generally weak. This is costly for individuals who prefer a smooth path of consumption and are averse to periods of unemployment or poverty (Schwellnus 2011).

Finally, during the last decade, Mexico has implemented a more ambitious and wide-ranging innovation policy aimed at getting closer to the technological frontier and generating higher levels of economic growth (Rodriguez-Pose and Villarreal 2015). By 2016, the expansion of economic activity was highly dependent on private consumption as low levels of investment and export demand were scarcely contributing to growth. In the medium term, economic and financial stability and an increase in external competitiveness, derived from the depreciation of the country’s currency, are expected to boost private investment, exports, and hence economic growth (World Bank 2016b).

In this context, it is very important to formulate an econometric approach in order to successfully predict Mexican economic activity, which takes into account a large number of macroeconomic and financial variables associated with the behavior of the economy. Hence, we use a large non-stationary DFM in which the variables are summarized in the common trends of the Mexican economy. These common trends are used in a FAVAR representation, evaluating the out-sample forecast error one and two steps ahead during a recent phase of the economy.

3 The models

In this section we introduce notation and describe the non-stationary DFM and the FAVAR model in order to use the common trends to predict a specific macroeconomic variable.

3.1 Non-stationary dynamic factor model

Suppose that N large economic time series \(Y_t = (y_{1t},\ldots , y_{Nt})^{\prime }\), observed from \(t=1,\ldots ,T\), are I(1) and any two series \(y_{it}\) and \(y_{jt}\) are cointegrated, such that the idiosyncratic component \(\varepsilon_t = (\varepsilon_{1t},\ldots , \varepsilon_{Nt})^{\prime }\) is stationary. In this case, and following Stock and Watson (1988), there is a common factor representation as follows:

$$Y_t = PF_t + \varepsilon_t,$$
(1)

where \(P=(p_{1}^{{\prime }},\ldots ,p_{N}^{{\prime }})^{{\prime }}\) is the \(N\times r\) (\(r < N\)) matrix of factor loadings, where \(p_{i}=(p_{i1},\ldots ,p_{ir})\) and \(F_{t}=(F_{1t},\ldots ,F_{rt})^{{\prime }}\) is the \(r \times 1\) vector of common factors, or in this case, the common trends.

Given that any two series of \(Y_t\) are cointegrated in the sense of Engle and Granger (1987), the dynamic of the common factors and the idiosyncratic components are the following:

$$F_t = F_{t-1} + \eta_t$$
(2)
$$\varepsilon_t = \varGamma (L)\varepsilon_{t-1} + a_t$$
(3)

where the factor disturbances, \(\eta_{t}=(\eta_{1t},\ldots ,\eta_{rt})^{{\prime }}\), are \(r\times 1\) vectors, distributed independently from the idiosyncratic noises for all leads and lags. Furthermore, \(\eta_{t}\) and \(a_{t}\) are white noises with positive definite covariance matrices \(\varSigma_{\eta }\) and \(\varSigma_{a}\), respectively. Additionally, \(\varGamma (L)\) collected the \(N\times N\) matrices containing the autoregressive parameters of the idiosyncratic components where L is the lag operator such that \(L^{k}\varepsilon_t = \varepsilon_{t-k}\). These autoregressive matrices satisfy the usual stationarity assumptions.

The DFM in Eqs. (1)–(3) is not identified because for any \(r\times r\) non-singular matrix H, the system can be expressed in terms of a new loading matrix and a new set of common factors as follows:

$$Y_t = P^{*}F^{*}_t + \varepsilon_t$$
(4)
$$F^{*}_t = F_{t-1}^{*} + \eta_t^{*} ,$$
(5)

where \(P^{*}=PH\), \(F^{*}_t = H^{-1}F_t\), and \(\eta_t^{*} = H^{-1}\eta_t\). The DFM in Eqs. (4) and (5) is observationally equivalent to that in Eqs. (1) and (2). A normalization is necessary to solve this identification problem and uniquely define the factors. In the context of PC factor extraction, it is common to impose the restriction \(P^{\prime }P/N = I_r\) and \(F^{\prime}F\) being diagonal, where \(F = (F_1,\ldots ,F_T)^{\prime }\) is a \(T\times r\) matrix of common factors. Alternatively, we can set the restrictions \(F^{\prime}F/T^2 = I_r\) and \(P^{\prime }P\) being diagonal; see Bai (2004) for identification issues in the non-stationary case.

In Eqs. (1)–(3), if \(\varGamma = 0\) and \(\varSigma_a\) is diagonal, then the DFM is known as strict; see Bai and Ng (2008). On the other hand, when \(\varGamma \ne 0\) and \(\varSigma_a\) is diagonal, there is serial correlation in the idiosyncratic noises and in this case the DFM is called exact; see Stock and Watson (2011). Chamberlain and Rothschild (1983) introduce the term approximate model when the idiosyncratic term does not need to have a diagonal covariance matrix. Forni et al. (2000) and Stock and Watson (2002a) generalize the approximate model, allowing for weak serial and cross-correlation. Furthermore, Bai and Ng (2002) and Bai (2003) also allow for heteroskedasticity in both the time and cross-sectional dimensions.

3.2 The factor-augmented autoregressive model

Once the non-stationary DFM is specified, we can use the common trends to predict a specific macroeconomic variable, denoted as \(x_t\); see Stock and Watson (2005), Banerjee et al. (2013), among many others. It is important to comment that if forecasting is the objective, although (\(x_t, F_t)^{\prime }\) are integrated or cointegrated, the FAVAR specification is quite convenient. Note that the optimal conditional expectation does not require stationarity or stability in the system. The theoretical justification is given by Lütkepohl (2006). More recently, Barigozzi et al. (2016) discuss several situations where a VAR estimated in levels is equivalent to a cointegrated VAR. Basically, when estimating a VAR in levels we can consistently estimate the parameters of a cointegrated VAR. Therefore, the FAVAR is provided as follows:

$$\left( \begin{array}{c} x_t \\ F_t \end{array} \right) = \varPhi (L) \left( \begin{array}{c} x_{t-1} \\ F_{t-1} \end{array} \right) + v_t,$$
(6)

where

$$\varPhi (L) = \left( \begin{array}{ccccc} \varPhi_{11}^{(k)} &{} \varPhi_{12}^{(k)}&{} \varPhi_{13}^{(k)} &{} \dots &{} \varPhi_{1r+1}^{(k)} \\ 0 &{} \varPhi_{22}^{(k)} &{} 0 &{} \dots &{} 0 \\ 0 &{} 0 &{} \varPhi_{33}^{(k)} &{} &{} 0 \\ \vdots &{} \vdots &{} &{} \ddots &{} \\ 0 &{} 0 &{} 0 &{} &{} \varPhi_{r+1r+1}^{(k)} \end{array} \right) L^{k+1},$$

for \(k = 1,\ldots , p\), where \(v_t \sim N(0, \varSigma_v)\). Intuitively, common economic trends that summarize its long-run behavior are used to predict a specific macroeconomic variable. For a similar representation but in the stationary context, see Bräuning and Koopman (2014). Note that expression (6) is the prediction equation; for example, assuming \(p = 1\), for any h step ahead, then

$$x_{t+h} = \varPhi_{11}x_{t-(h+1)} + \varPhi_{12}F_{1,t-(h+1)} + \cdots + \varPhi_{1r+1}F_{r+1,t-(h+1)} + v_{t+h}.$$
(7)

Additionally, we can introduce deterministic components and seasonal and exogenous variables in Eq. (6).

4 Estimation

The estimation of the parameters of Eq. (6) is obtained using restricted ordinary least squares (OLS). Furthermore, it is necessary to define the number of common factors and their factor estimates. In this section we describe some traditional methods to determine the number of non-stationary common factors. Additionally, we describe PC factor extraction and comment on an alternative method to estimate the common factors, known in literature as PLS.

4.1 Determining the number of factors

It was previously assumed that r is known, however in practice it is frequently necessary to estimate it. In this subsection we describe two procedures to determine r in the context of large DFMs, namely the Onatski (2010) procedure and the ratio of eigenvalues proposed by Ahn and Horenstein (2013). There are other alternatives to determine r, the Bai and Ng (2002) information criteria, the respective correction proposed by Alessi et al. (2010), and the procedure carried out by Kapetanios (2010), among many other approaches. Moreover, in the context of non-stationary DFMs, Ergemen and Rodriguez-Caballero (2016) use the procedure given by Hallin and Liska (2007) to determine the number of regional and global factors allowing fractional differencing in \(Y_t\). However, and following Corona et al. (2017a), they show that the finite sample performance of the proposed procedures in this paper exhibits a good performance when we use data in first differences or levels and the common factors are I(1).Footnote 4

4.1.1 Onatski (2010) procedure

The Onatski (2010) procedure is based on the behavior of two adjacent eigenvalues of \({\hat{\varSigma }}_Y = T^{-1}Y^{\prime }Y\), for \(j = 1, \ldots , r_{\max }\). Intuitively, it is reasonable that when N and T tend to infinity, the difference between \({\hat{\lambda }}_j - {\hat{\lambda }}_{j+1}\) tends to zero while \({\hat{\lambda }}_r - {\hat{\lambda }}_{r+1}\) diverges to infinity, where \({\hat{\lambda }}_i\) is the i-largest eigenvalue of \({\hat{\varSigma }}_Y\). Onatski (2010) points out the necessity of determining a “sharp” threshold that separates convergent and divergent eigenvalues, denoted as \(\delta\). The author gives the empirical procedure to determine the threshold and in practice, this approach is more robust in presence of non-stationarity and when the factors are weak or when the proportion of variance attributed to the idiosyncratic components is larger than the variance of the common component. We denote this estimator as \({\hat{r}}_{\mathrm{ED}} = \max \lbrace j \le r_{\max } : {\hat{\lambda }}_j - {\hat{\lambda }}_{j + 1} \ge \delta \rbrace.\).

4.1.2 The Ahn and Horenstein (2013) ratios of eigenvalues

Ahn and Horenstein (2013) develop the consistency of the estimation of r when they use the ratio of two adjacent eigenvalues of \({\hat{\varSigma }}_Y\) under the traditional assumptions of PC factor extraction. The two criteria provided by the authors are based on maximizing with respect to \(j = 1, \ldots , r_{\max }\) the following ratios:

$$\text{ER}(j)=\frac{{\hat{\lambda }}_{j}}{{\hat{\lambda }}_{j+1}},$$
(8)
$$\text{GR}(j)=\frac{ \ln (1+{\hat{\lambda }}_{j}^{*})}{\ln (1+{\hat{\lambda }}_{j+1}^{*})},$$
(9)

where \({\hat{\lambda }}_{0}=\frac{1}{m}\sum_{i=1}^{m}{\hat{\lambda }}_{j}/\ln (m)\) and \({\hat{\lambda }}_{j}^{*}={\hat{\lambda }}_{j}/\sum_{i=k+1}^{m}\hat{\lambda }_{i}\). The value of \({\hat{\lambda }}_{0}\) has been chosen following the definition of Ahn and Horenstein (2013), according to which \({\hat{\lambda }}_{0}\rightarrow 0\) and \(m{\hat{\lambda }}_{0}\rightarrow \infty\) as \(m\rightarrow \infty .\)

4.2 Principal components factor extraction

The most popular method to extract static common factors is based on PC given that it does not require assumptions of the error distribution, and the estimation of the common component is consistent, among many other properties; see Bai (2003). This procedure separates the common component from the idiosyncratic noises by considering a cross-sectional averaging of the variables within \(Y_t\) such that when N and T tend simultaneously to infinity, the weighted averages of the idiosyncratic noises converge to zero, with only the linear combinations of the factors remaining. Therefore, this method requires that the cumulative effects of the common component increase proportionally with N, while the eigenvalues associated with the idiosyncratic components remain bounded.

The PC estimator of \(F_t\) can be derived as the solution to the following least squares problem:

$$V_r(P,F)=\min_{F_1,\ldots ,F_T,P}(NT)^{-1}\sum_{t=1}^{T}(Y_t-PF_t)^{\prime }(Y_t-PF_t)$$
(10)

subject to the restrictions \(F^{\prime }F/T^2 = I_r\) and \(P^{\prime }P\) being diagonal, where \(F = (F_{1},\ldots , F_{T})^{\prime }\) is a \(r \times T\) matrix of common trends. The minimization problem in (10) is equivalent to maximizing tr\([F^{\prime }(YY^{\prime })F]\) where \(Y = (Y_1,\ldots ,Y_T)^{\prime }\) with the dimension \(T\times N\). This maximization problem is solved by setting \(\hat{F}\) equal to T times the eigenvectors corresponding to the r largest eigenvalues of the \(T\times T\) matrix \(YY^{\prime }\). The corresponding PC estimator of P is given byFootnote 5:

$$\hat{P} = \frac{Y^{\prime } \hat{F}}{T^2}.$$
(11)

Bai (2003) deduces that the rate of convergence and the limiting distributions of the estimated factors, factor loadings and common component is the stationary DFM when the cross-section and time dimensions tend towards infinity. Under the assumptions considered in this paper, Bai (2004) shows the consistency of \(\hat{F}_t\), \(\hat{P},\) and the common component. The finite sample performance of \(\hat{F}_t\) is analyzed by Bai (2004) and recently by Corona et al. (2017b). The first author concludes that \(\hat{F}_t\) is a close estimation of \(F_t\) when the idiosyncratic errors are stationary and even if the sample size is moderately small (i.e., \(N = 100\) and \(T = 40\)). The second authors consider structure dependence in the idiosyncratic errors and show that when the idiosyncratic errors are I(0) we can obtain close estimations of \(F_t\) even if N is small and the variance of \(\varepsilon_t\) is large. When the idiosyncratic errors are I(1), \(\hat{F}_t\) works poorly. In this case, it is convenient to use the estimator given by Bai and Ng (2004).Footnote 6 Other alternatives to estimate the common factors without differencing them are given by Barigozzi et al. (2016) and Corona et al. (2017b).

Note that the estimation of \(F_t\) disregards the dynamic of Eqs. (2) and (3). The reason for this is that we estimate the common factors from static representation in the factor model. Corona et al. (2017b) incorporate the dynamic of Eq. (2) in a second step to obtain smooth estimates of the common factors using the Kalman filter. However, in this study we focus on a large DFM from static representation. For a technical discussion of the analogies and differences between static and dynamic representation, see for example Bai and Ng (2007). Thus, our approach is related to Bai (2004) and Bai and Ng (2004), who study non-stationarity in DFMs under a static representation.

4.3 Partial least squares

In addition to the estimation of \(F_t\) by PC, we consider the PLS estimation, which takes into account the effect of a dependent variable. In a similar manner to Fuentes et al. (2015), we estimate the common factors in economic time series using PLS, denoted as \({\tilde{F}}_t\). Intuitively, the idea is to find the orthogonal latent variables that maximize the covariance between Y and \(x = (x_1, \dots , x_T)^{\prime }\). The estimation process is iterative, and the first step consists in the eigenvalue decomposition of the following \(T \times T\) matrix:

$$M = Yxx^{\prime }Y^{\prime }$$
(12)

Then, the first common factor, \({\tilde{F}}_{1t}\), is the first eigenvector associated to the first eigenvalue of M. The second common factor is estimated from the residual matrix of \(e = Y - B{\tilde{F}}_1^{\prime }\). To obtain the following common factors, the process is repeated \(r-2\) steps using the \({\tilde{F}}_{1t}, \dots , {\tilde{F}}_{r-1t}\) common factors in each step.

5 Empirical analysis

In this section we present the data from the Mexican economy used in this study, describe the methodology to evaluate the accuracy of the common trends in order to predict the Mexican economy, determine the number of common trends, and analyze their dynamic by evaluating the performance of the FAVAR model proposed in Sect. 2 with respect to benchmark models.

5.1 Data

Initially, we consider 511 macroeconomic and financial variables obtained from the Banco de Información Económica (BIE) of the Insituto Nacional de Geografía y Estadística (INEGI), Mexico’s national statistical agency. The analysis covers from March 2005 to April 2016, hence, \(T = 133\). The blocks of variables are considered according to the INEGI division, and additionally, we compare this division with respect to the National Institute’s Global Econometric Model, which considers nine blocks with a total of 67 variables.Footnote 7

According to our approach, it is necessary that all variables are integrated of order one, so that, if factors are found, these are the common trends of the observations. In this case, we consider only I(1) variables according to the Augmented Dickey–Fuller (ADF) test.Footnote 8 When needed, the time series have been deseasonalized and corrected by outliers using X-13ARIMA-SEATS developed by the US Census Bureau.Footnote 9 Following Stock and Watson (2005), outliers are substituted by the median of the five previous observations.

Finally, according to these non-stationary conditions, we work with the following database of \(N = 211\) variables (number between parentheses)Footnote 10:

  • Balance of trade (19)

  • Consumer confidence (18)

  • Consumption (9)

  • Economic activity (13)

  • Employment (5)

  • Financial (35)

  • Industrial (58)

  • International (17)

  • Investment (8)

  • Miscellaneous (18)

  • Prices (11).Footnote 11

Furthermore, we define \(x_t\) as the Global Index of Economic Activity (IGAE, Indicador Global de la Actividad Económica).Footnote 12

5.2 Estimating the common trends

We apply the criteria described in this article to detect the number of factors. We use an \(r_{\max } = 11\). The results indicate that \({\hat{r}}_{\mathrm{ER}} = {\hat{r}}_{\mathrm{GR}} = 2\) and \({\hat{r}}_{\mathrm{ED}} = 5\).Footnote 13 Given that Onatski (2010) is more robust in the presence of non-stationarity, see Corona et al. (2017a), we work with this number of factors.Footnote 14

Figure 1 plots the results of the ratios and differences of eigenvalues with the respective threshold. Note that, intuitively, it is congruent that the ratio of eigenvalues of Ahn and Horenstein (2013) determines one and two common factors, given that the first and second differences of eigenvalues are large, while the others are practically zero. However, the estimation of the “sharp” threshold is one of the main contributions from Onatski (2010), which as we have mentioned, consistently separates convergent and divergent eigenvalues. Furthermore, the five common factors explain 79.19\(\%\) of the total variability. Specifically, the first common factor explains 46.14\(\%\), the second 19.59\(\%\), the third 6.2\(\%\), the fourth 4.75\(\%,\) and the fifth 2.51\(\%\).

Fig. 1
figure 1

Determination of the number of factors through the Onatski (2010) procedure, \({\hat{\lambda }}_i - {\hat{\lambda }}_{i+1}\) (top panel) and ratio of eigenvalues (bottom panel), \({\hat{\lambda }}_{i+1}/{\hat{\lambda }}_{i}\), for \(i = 1,\ldots , 6\)

Figure 2 plots the behaviors between \(\ln x_t\) (deseasonalized) and each common factor extracted by PC and PLS. We observe that the first common factor, for each procedure, is similar to \(\ln x_t\) with contemporaneous linear correlations of 0.95 for PC and 0.96 for PLS. The second common factors are slightly correlated with \(\ln x_t\), having contemporaneous correlations of 0.13 and 0.08 for PC and PLS, respectively. On the other hand, \({\tilde{F}}_{3t}\) and \({\tilde{F}}_{5t}\) have an inverse behavior, although the correlations with respect to \(\ln x_t\) are around \(-0.01.\) In the other cases, the estimated common factors are positively related to \(\ln x_t\) but the linear correlations are drastically small. These facts indicate that contemporaneously, only the first two common factors are associated with economic activity. It is interesting to mention that these two factors explain 65.73% of the total variability. Note that it is complicated to establish the predictive capacity between the common factors, and it is necessary to evaluate it in the FAVAR model. Furthermore, it is clear that the sample period includes the economic crisis of 2008–2009; however, Stock and Watson (2011) show that the PC estimator of the factors is consistent even with certain types of breaks or time variation in the factor loadings.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Top left panel \(\langle lnx_t, F_{1t} \rangle\), top right panel \(\langle \ln x_t, F_{2t} \rangle\), middle left panel \(\langle \ln x_t, F_{3t} \rangle\), the middle right panel \(\langle \ln x_t, F_{4t} \rangle\) , and bottom left panel \(\langle \ln x_t, F_{5t} \rangle\). The blue color refers to PC and the red color to PLS (color figure online)

Figure 3 shows the weighted average contribution of each variable block in the common factors estimated by PC. Each color bar represents the contribution of the percentage of explanation of each variable group with respect to each common factor, denoted as follows:

$$\hat{\mu }_{jg} = \sum_{i_g = 1}^{N_g}|\hat{p}_{i_gjg}|/N_g \quad \text{for } j = 1, \ldots r, \text{ and } g = 1, \ldots , G,$$

where \(\hat{p}_{i_gjg}\) is the loading weight of each group of variables; G is the number of blocks of variables; and \(N_g\) is the number of variables in each group. Specifically, the order of the groups of variables is computed as \(r^{-1}\sum_{j=1}^{r}{\hat{\lambda }}_{j}\hat{\mu }_{jg}\) where \({\hat{\lambda }}_j\) is the variance contribution of each common factor. The block that most explains the common factors is the miscellaneous group, economic activity, and balance of trade blocks. On the other hand, prices, employment, and consumer confidence are the least relevant groups of variables. Note that this importance is in terms of the loading contribution and it is not interpreted as predictive power. Specifically, the first common factor is more correlated with the IGAE of tertiary activities (0.99), the second common factor with the economic situation with respect to last year (0.94), the third common factor with oil exports (0.78), the fourth common factor with edification (0.70), and the fifth common factor with the food industry (0.53).

Fig. 3
figure 3

Weighted mean \(\hat{\mu }_{jg} = \sum_{i_g = 1}^{G}|\hat{p}_{i_gjg}|/N_g \text{ for } j = 1,\ldots , r, \text{ and } g = 1, \ldots , G,\) where G is the number of blocks of variables and \(N_g\) is the number of variables in each group

In order to evaluate if the common factors are the common trends of \(x_t\), we carry out the cointegration exercise. The possible cointegration relationship is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} {\hat{v}}_t= & {} \ln x_t - \underset{(0.0000)}{4.6369} - \underset{(0.0000)}{0.0719}\hat{F}_{1t} - \underset{(0.0000)}{0.0098}\hat{F}_{2t} \nonumber \\ &-\,\underset{(0.0000)}{0.0003}\hat{F}_{3t} + \underset{(0.0000)}{0.0008}\hat{F}_{4t} + \underset{(0.0000)}{0.0002}\hat{F}_{5t}. \end{aligned}$$
(13)

We estimate the ADF test with its respective p value (in parentheses), obtaining the following results:

$$\text{ADF test}{:} -3.4382\ (0.01)$$

Then, we can verify that the common trends of a large dataset of the economic variables are cointegrated with economic activity. Furthermore and following Bai and Ng (2004), first, we carry out a Panel Analysis of Non-stationarity in Idiosyncratic and Common Components (PANIC) on the idiosyncratic errors obtained using the “differencing and recumulating” method in order to disentangle the non-stationarity in this component. Second, we apply a PANIC to the idiosyncratic components estimated using data in levels as we have proposed in this study. In the first analysis, we obtain a p value of 0.1171 while in the second, we obtain a p value of 0.0000. Although in the first case \({\hat{\varepsilon }}_t\) is statistically non-stationary, the p value is around the uncertainty zone. Furthermore, we apply the variant of the ADF test proposed by Bai (2004) with the aim of detecting how many of the five common factors are non-stationary. As we expected, the tests show that the five common factors are non-stationary. Therefore, we conclude that the idiosyncratic terms are stationary and the common factors are non-stationary; hence, we can also argue that the elements of \(Y_t\) are cointegrated and the common factors are the common trends of \(Y_t\) and \(x_t\).

Note that Eq. (13) is the static version of Eq. (7). The goal of this exercise is to determine whether \(F_t\) are the common trends of \(x_t\) and \(Y_t\). We use this information to forecast the target variable with the FAVAR model presented in Sect. 2.

5.3 Evaluating the use of common trends to predict Mexican economic activity

It is important to have an empirical strategy to adequately predict the target variable. Consequently, with the aim of selecting the forecast model, we consider all possibilities of FAVAR models, \(\sum_{i=1}^r {}^rC_i\times 396\), where \(^rC_i\) is the binomial coefficient \(\left( {\begin{array}{c}r\\ i\end{array}}\right)\) and 396 is obtained as the product of 11 seasonal dummies (3–12 and none), 3 deterministic specifications in the FAVAR model (none, constant and trend), and 12 lags (1–12). Therefore, the lag order, the seasonal dummies, the deterministic component, and the factors are directly determined by minimum out-sample forecast error. The training sample covers from March 2015 to April 2016, such that we forecast 12 periods (1 year) for \(h = 2\). This forecast period is one of relative economic and political stability in Mexico. For example, during this time frame, the annual growth rate of Mexico’s GDP in any quarter was never lower than 2.3% and never higher than 2.8% (INEGI 2016). Moreover, the country’s economic performance tends to be more volatile in times close to presidential elections in Mexico, and to a lesser degree in the US, which do not coincide with our forecast period. Statistically, this period represents around 10% of the number of observations and discounting the degrees of freedom, we are able to represent 25% of \(T-K\) where K is the number of parameters in the FAVAR model.

For each model, we compute the forecast error. The forecasts are dynamic, so that we update \(T+1\) in each month. We selected the model that minimizes the Root Mean Square Error (RMSE).Footnote 15 Furthermore, we focus on the models that give a forecast error lower than a threshold. This threshold is determined directly using Eickmeier et al. (2014) as a reference. In their work they predict several macroeconomic variables using FAVAR models, FAVAR-tv, FAVAR-tv with stochastic volatility errors and univariate models. For one and two step ahead, forecasting the US GDP, the RMSE values in in-sample forecasts are 0.76 and 0.80 considering all periods for \(h = 1\) and \(h = 2,\) respectively. However, we select a threshold of 0.5 to obtain more accurate forecasts. Note that, if we predict \(\varDelta \ln x_t\) for the first step ahead, the forecast error is \(e_{T + 1} = (\ln x_{T + 1} - \ln x_{T}) - (\ln x_{T+1}^{f} - \ln x_T) = \ln x_{T + 1} - \ln x_{T+1}^{f}\), i.e., it is equivalent to forecasting the level of the first step ahead. Therefore, we focus on the levels of the IGAE.

5.4 Using common trends to predict Mexican economic activity

First, in order to descriptively evaluate the predictive capacity of each variable, we calculate the cross-correlation between \(y_{it-h}\) and \(x_t\) and consequently:

$$\rho ^{*}_h = \text{corr}(y_{it-h},x_t)|\lbrace \max (h \le 12:\text{Prob}(\text{corr}(y_{it-h}, x_t))<\alpha )\rbrace,$$

where \(\alpha = 0.05\). Figure 4 plots the results of the previous equation. Note that the top panel plots the \(\rho ^{*}_h\) with the confidence interval. The middle panel shows their corresponding maximum significant lag, \(\max (h \le 12:\text{Prob}(\text{corr}(y_{it-h}, x_t))<\alpha )\) and bottom panel presents the mean absolute correlations for each block of variables. Note that the block of variables most highly correlated with the future of \(x_t\) is the miscellaneous one. It is interesting to note that all significant variables of this block are positively correlated with the IGAE. Other interesting variable blocks are the economic activity and financial groups. On the other hand, the blocks least correlated with the future of \(x_t\) are consumer confidence, employment, and prices.

Fig. 4
figure 4

The top panel plots the \(\rho ^{*}_h\) with the confidence interval. The middle panel shows their corresponding maximum significant lag, \(\max ( h \le 12:\text{Prob}(\text{corr}(y_{it-h}, x_t)) < 0.05),\) and the bottom panel presents the mean absolute correlations for each block of variables

It is important to state that the PANIC carried out on the idiosyncratic errors and common factors shows that the elements of \(Y_t\) are cointegrated; hence, it is reasonable to expect that the correlations between \(y_{it}\) and \(x_t\) are not spurious.

Once the models are estimated, we review the forecast errors lower than the threshold in the training sample. Figure 5 plots the historical behavior of the RMSE for the selected predictive models. The top panel plots the RMSE for \(h = 1\). Note that the PC gives slightly more accurate results than PLS. Furthermore, the dispersion of the RMSE for PLS is larger than PLS and neither approach presents outliers. The bottom panel shows the results for \(h = 2\). We can see that for both procedures, the forecast errors are slightly increased with respect to \(h = 1\). It is interesting to mention that for both h the tails from both procedures are intercepted. This graph is important because this behavior is expected for the following two predicted months.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Box plots for the RMSE of out-sample forecasts for the selected models. The top panel is \(h = 1\) and the bottom panel \(h = 2\). The blue color refers to PC and the red color to PLS (color figure online)

Using the models from Fig. 5 we predict two steps ahead: May and June 2016. Note that we have n models, such that it is necessary to combine the forecasts. Thus we propose a weighted average, obtaining loadings similar to the PLS procedure by solving the following optimization problem:

$$\rho_1 = \underset{w,b}{\max \text{cor}}(X^{f}w, xb) \quad \text{subject to} \quad \text{Var}(X^{f}w) = \text{Var}(xb) = 1,$$

where \(w = (w_1,\ldots , w_n)\). In order to normalize the loading weights, we carry out the following scaling: \(w^{*} = n(\sum_{i = 1}^{n}w_i)^{-1}w\), such that the loading weights are between 0 and 1. Figure 6 shows the forecast density, the predictions, and the observed data. We plot the confidence interval to 95\(\%\). Note that for \(h = 1\), PLS is more accurate than PC, while for \(h = 2\), PLS is less accurate. The models are centered on the mean of the distribution. Moreover, the forecast density acquires the observed data. Furthermore, focusing on \(h = 2\), the distribution of PC has two modes and the predicted data tend towards the center of the distribution. On the other hand, for PLS, it tends towards the median of the distribution.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Forecast densities, forecast points (red color), and observed data (blue color) (color figure online)

An interesting question is: which common trends are helpful to reduce forecast error? To this end, we compute the following coefficients through OLS:

$$\partial e_t | D_{ti} = 1< 0 \quad \text{and} \quad \text{Prob}(\partial e_t | D_{ti} = 1) < 0.10 \qquad \text{for } i = 1,\ldots , N_{\mathrm{m}},$$

where \(N_{\mathrm{m}}\) is the number of models for each procedure. In other words, we carry out a linear regression between the forecast errors according to each procedure and dummy variables that specify the combination of common trends \(F_{1t}\), \(F_{2t}\), \(F_{3t}\), \(F_{4t},\) and \(F_{5t}\) for both procedures. Figure 7 plots the result for each procedure in each h. We can see that, in PC, \(F_{1t}\) is a very important common factor to reduce the forecast error for \(h = 1\), whereas \(F_{1t}\), \(F_{2t}\), \(F_{4t},\) and \(F_{5t}\) are important for \(h = 2\). Furthermore, in the PLS approach \(F_{1t}\), \(F_{2t}\), \(F_{4t},\) and \(F_{5t}\) are relevant common factors for \(h = 1\) whereas \(F_{1t},\) and \(F_{2t}\) are for \(h = 2\). In fact, for both procedures the interaction of all common factors is important to reduce the forecast errors. This result completes the conclusions when we analyze Figs. 1 and 4, where all common factors are helpful to reduce the forecast errors.

Fig. 7
figure 7

Effects of variables on forecast errors: \(\partial e_t | D_{ti} = 1 < 0\) and \(\text{Prob}(\partial e_t | D_{ti} = 1) < 0.10\). The blue color refers to PC and the red color to PLS (color figure online)

In order to evaluate the forecast accuracy in “real time,” we predict two steps ahead (May and June 2016). Figure 8 shows the forecast accuracy of the following models: (i) PC, (ii) PC using only factors that contribute to reducing the forecast error denoted as PC (2), (iii) PLS, (iv) PLS (2), (v) the average between the first and third models, and (vi) the average between the second and fourth models. We can see that for \(h = 1\) PLS, PLS (2) and the forecast average of PC and PLS are the most accurate model with 0 forecast error for May 2016. For \(h = 1\), PC gives a forecast error of 0.1 in June 2016. In conclusion, and with reference to Fig. 5, the results are as expected given that PC and PLS give forecast errors lower than the selected threshold.

Fig. 8
figure 8

Observed forecast error for May 2016 (\(h = 1\)) and June 2016 (\(h = 2\)). PC (blue color), PC 2 (deep blue color), PLS (red color), PC 2 (deep red color), average of forecasts (gray color), and average 2 of forecasts (black color). The number 2 indicates that the models only considered the variables that satisfy \(\partial e_t | D_{ti} = 1 < 0\) and \(\text{Prob}(\partial e_t | D_{ti} = 1) < 0.10\) (color figure online)

It is interesting to mention the historical behavior of the models. Hence, we first analyze the RMSE of the benchmark models: the Autoregressive Integrated Moving Average (ARIMA) and the macroeconomic diffusion index (Stock and Watson 2002b). Figure 9 plots the results for the out-sample training. For \(h = 1\), we observe that the RMSE interval is between 0.82 and 1.07 for the ARIMA model, while for the macroeconomic diffusion index it is between 0.62 and 0.83. For \(h = 2\) the errors are slightly reduced in both cases; however, the macroeconomic diffusion index has better results. Hence, note that the inclusion of the factor in linear models reduces the forecast error. Then, we would expect the FAVAR models to show a small RMSE.Footnote 16

Fig. 9
figure 9

Forecast Errors for benchmark models: April 2015–2016. ARIMA (red color) and Macroeconomic diffusion index (blue color). The top left panel plots \(h = 1\) and the bottom right panel plots \(h = 2\) (color figure online)

Figure 10 plots step-by-step the forecast errors of the FAVAR models considering the approach presented in this work. Note that the RMSE interval of PC for \(h = 1\) is between 0.27 and 0.67 and for \(h = 2\) between 0.29 and 0.59. The RMSE mean values are 0.47 and 0.44 for each h, respectively. Note that in both h, February 2016 is the outlier forecast error. On the other hand, for PLS and \(h = 1\), the forecast errors are between 0.34 and 0.60 and for \(h = 2\), the confidence interval is between 0.3 and 0.64. In this case, the mean of RMSE is 0.47 for each h, respectively. Note that the improvement with respect to the ARIMA model and macroeconomic diffusion index is relevant, above all when the factors are estimated using PC. Note that the forecast errors are very similar between PC and PLS.

Fig. 10
figure 10

Forecast Errors for FAVAR models: April 2015–2016. PC (red color) and PLS (blue color). The top left panel plots \(h = 1\) and the bottom right panel plots \(h = 2\) (color figure online)

A question of interest is: are the models consistent through the training sample? We can obtain different models in each step ahead, in which case the consistency of the predictors may be questionable. Taking into account only the selected models, we can observe in Fig. 11 that all models are robust in \(h = 1\). In fact, 76\(\%\) of the models are within the threshold and for \(h = 2\), the behavior of the predictions is similar to May 2016. Note that the predictions for May and June 2016 are carried out with information up to April 2016. Hence, we present the forecast in \(h = 1\) for May 2016 and \(h = 2\) for June 2016. The model is not updated as in the previous forecasts. It is interesting to note that February 2016 was the most complicated month to predict; however, the robustness of the selected models is reasonable. The reason why February 2016 was a complicated month to predict can be explained by the fact that this month has 29 days, and the seasonal variables and the dynamics between the variables do not account for this effect.

Fig. 11
figure 11

Robustness of selected models. Red points indicate that the model satisfies the empirical threshold in the specific forecast month. A red cross indicates that there is no information to compute the statistic (color figure online)

6 Conclusions and further research

In this paper we estimated the common trends of the Mexican economy using a large dataset of macroeconomic variables. Using cointegration concepts, we estimated the common trends using I(1) variables through PC, determining the number of common factors according to the Onatski (2010) and the Ahn and Horenstein (2013) procedures. Alternatively, we estimated the common factors using PLS.

We find that 211 macroeconomic and financial variables can be summarized in at most \({\hat{r}} = 5\) common trends, which are cointegrated with Mexican economic activity. Furthermore, we use the common trends in a FAVAR model with the aim of predicting Mexican economic activity. We statistically evaluate the predictive capacity of the common trends, where we can see that each common factor reduces the forecast error. Additionally, we observe that the forecast error is reduced with respect to the ARIMA and factor-augmented regressions, such that the common trends are useful to predict Mexican economic activity.

An important conclusion is that the macroeconomic common trends can be used in more sophisticated models in order to reduce the forecast errors. Additionally, note that in this study we used data in levels in order to estimate the common factors. This is empirical evidence on the use of DFMs when we do not transform the data to stationarity.

Economically, the more relevant groups of variables in the determination of the common trends are the miscellaneous group, the economic activity, balance of trade, and the industrial sector. The first group of variables basically comprises tourism information and variables related to the automotive industry. In this context, the behaviors of the external sector and internal demand are very important to predict the behavior of the global economy. It is reasonable to expect that external uncertainty and disincentives in the internal market can be dangerous for future economic growth. In other words, these groups of variables indicate the future movements of Mexican economic activity.

A future line of research is to use the common trends in factor error correction models (FECM), and FAVAR with time-varying coefficients, among many other models, combining the predictions with different combinations of forecasting methods. Furthermore, we consider a unit root test that takes into account the structural break that occurred between 2008 and 2009 in order to refine the procedure to select I(1) variables. Consequently, it is interesting to study the non-stationarity of the estimated common factors in the presence of breaks. Additionally, we will take into account the possibility of sparse cointegration for forecasting proposes.

Notes

  1. The common factors are equivalent to the common trends when we assume a static representation in the factor model. Barigozzi et al. (2016) develop the econometric theory for non-stationary DFMs with large datasets under different assumptions of the dynamic of the common factors.

  2. Certainly, macroeconomic diffusion indexes are related to DFMs. However, in this study we make a distinction between multivariate predictive approaches and the classic diffusion index forecasts given by Stock and Watson (2002b). Furthermore, we focus on a DFM from a static point of view. Once the common factors are estimated and their non-stationarity disentangled, we use the factors in the proposed FAVAR representation.

  3. A related study is Caruso (2015), who examines the flow of conjunctural data relevant to assess the state of Mexico’s economy. Specifically, the author exploits the information embedded in macroeconomic news from both Mexico and the US, in a model constructed to nowcast Mexican real Gross Domestic Product (GDP) based on DFMs and Kalman filters.

  4. Alternatively, Bai (2004) proposes an information criteria for data in levels, modifying the \(\text{PC}(k)\) information criteria of Bai and Ng (2002) by multiplying the penalty function by \(\alpha_T = T/[4 \log \log (T)].\)

  5. Alternatively, if we choose the restrictions \(P^{\prime }P/N = I_r\) and \(F^{\prime }F\) being diagonal, the estimator of the matrix of factor loadings, \(\hat{P}\), is \(\sqrt{N}\) times the eigenvectors corresponding to the r largest eigenvalues of the \(N\times N\) matrix \(Y^{\prime }Y\), with estimated factor matrix \(\hat{F} = Y\hat{P}/N\). The difference is only computational, these latest restrictions are less costly when \(T > N\), whereas \(F^{\prime }F/T^2 = I_r\) with \(P^{\prime }P\) being diagonal are less costly when \(T < N\).

  6. According to Bai and Ng (2004), if \(\varepsilon_t\) is not stationary, it is necessary to differentiate \(Y_t\) to consistently estimate \(F_t\) using \(\hat{F}_t = \sum_{s=1}^t\hat{f}_s\) where \(\hat{f}_t\) is the PC factor estimated when using data in first differences.

  7. https://nimodel.niesr.ac.uk.

  8. See Barigozzi et al. (2016) for a similar approach.

  9. https://cran.r-project.org/web/packages/seasonal.pdf.

  10. See Annex with the description of each block of variables included.

  11. It is well known that the prices can be I(2). In our sample period seven prices are I(2) and they are differenced.

  12. Note that the block of economic activity includes the components of the aggregate IGAE. Hence, this specific variable is not included in the block.

  13. Additionally, we estimate the Bai and Ng (2002) information criteria using data in levels and first-differenced data. In both cases, the three criteria tend to \({\hat{r}} = r_{\max }\).

  14. For the US economy, Alessi et al. (2010) determine six common factors using the database from Stock and Watson (2005).

  15. As we have mentioned in the introduction, the goal of this paper is to forecast Mexican economic activity. To this end, we have two measures: quarterly, GDP; and monthly, IGAE. In an early analysis, we prove that IGAE is perfectly correlated with GDP. In this case, given the monthly frequency data, it is more convenient to forecast the IGAE, with \(x_t\) as the target variable.

  16. Alternatively, we can consider RMSE in terms of benchmark models like several authors. However, we decide to use the RMSE to easily verify whether the FAVAR models give RMSEs lower than the selected threshold of 0.5.

References

  • Ahn S, Horenstein A (2013) Eigenvalue ratio test for the number of factors. Econometrica 81(3):1203–1227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alessi L, Barigozzi M, Capasso M (2010) Improved penalization for determining the number of factors in approximate factor models. Stat Probab Lett 80(1):1806–1813

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bai J (2003) Inferential theory for factor models of large dimensions. Econometrica 71(1):135–171

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bai J (2004) Estimating cross-section common stochastic trends in nonstationary panel data. J Econom 122(1):137–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bai J, Ng S (2002) Determining the number of factors in approximate factor models. Econometrica 70(1):191–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bai J, Ng S (2004) A PANIC attack on unit roots and cointegration. Econometrica 72(4):1127–1177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bai J, Ng S (2007) Determining the number of primitive shocks in factor models. J Bus Econ Stat 25(1):52–60

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bai J, Ng S (2008) Large dimensional factor analysis. Found Trends Econom 3(2):89–163

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee A, Marcellino M, Masten I (2013) Structural factor error correction models: cointegration in large-scale structural FAVAR models. Bocconi University and CEPR, Working Paper

  • Banerjee A, Marcellino M, Masten I (2014) Forecasting with factor-augmented error correction models. Int J Forecast 30(3):589–612

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barigozzi M, Lippi M, Luciani M (2016) Non-stationary dynamic factor models for large datasets. Finance and Economics Discussion Series 024

  • Boivin J, Ng S (2006) Are more data always better for factor analysis? J Econom 132(1):169–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bräuning F, Koopman SJ (2014) Forecasting macroeconomic variables using collapsed dynamic factor analysis. Int J Forecast 30(3):572–584

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breitung J, Choi I (2013) Factor models. In: Hashimzade N, Thorthon MA (eds) Handbook of research methods and applications in empirical macroeconomics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham (UK)

  • Caruso A (2015) Nowcasting Mexican GDP. ECARES Working Paper 2015-40

  • Chamberlain G, Rothschild M (1983) Arbitrage factor structure, and mean–variance analysis of large asset markets. Econometrica 51(1):1281–1304

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corona F, Poncela P, Ruiz E (2017a) Determining the number of factors after stationary univariate transformations. Empir Econ 53:351–372

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corona F, Poncela P, Ruiz E (2017b) Estimating non-stationary common factors: implications for risk sharing. UC3M Working Papers Statistics and Econometrics 17(09)

  • Dougherty S (2015) Boosting growth and reducing informality in Mexico. OECD Economics Department Working Papers 1188

  • Duy TA, Thoma MA (1998) Modeling and forecasting cointegrated variables: some practical experience. J Econ Bus 50(1):291–307

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eickmeier S, Ziegler C (2008) How good are dynamic factor models at forecasting output and inflation? A meta-analytic approach. J Forecast 27(3):237–265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eickmeier S, Lemke W, Marcellino M (2014) Classical time-varying FAVAR models—estimation, forecasting and structural analysis. J R Stat Soc 178(3):493–533

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engle RF, Granger CWJ (1987) Co-integration and error correction: representation, estimation, and testing. Econometrica 55(1):251–276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ergemen YE, Rodriguez-Caballero CV (2016) A dynamic multi-level factor model with long-range dependence. CREATES Research Paper 23

  • Forni M, Hallin M, Lippi M, Reichlin L (2000) The generalized dynamic-factor model: identification and estimation. Rev Econ Stat 82(4):540–554

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fuentes J, Poncela P, Rodrguez J (2015) Sparse partial least squares in time series for macroeconomic forecasting. J Appl Econom 30(4):576–595

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geweke J (1977) The dynamic factor analysis of economic time series. In: Aigner DJ, Goldberger AS (eds) Latent variables in socio-economic models. North-Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Giannone D, Reichlin L, Small D (2008) Nowcasting: the real-time informational content of macroeconomic data. J Monet Econ 55(4):665–676

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gonzalo J, Granger CWJ (1995) Estimation of common long-memory components in cointegrated systems. J Bus Econ Stat 13(1):27–35

    Google Scholar 

  • Hallin M, Liska R (2007) Determining the number of factors in the general dynamic factor model. J Am Stat Assoc 102:603–617

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanson G (2010) Why isnt Mexico rich? J Econ Lit 48(4):987–1004

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hindrayanto I, Koopman SJ, de Winter J (2016) Forecasting and nowcasting economic growth in the euro area using factor models. Int J Forecast 32(4):1284–1305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • INEGI (2016) Producto interno bruto de méxico durante el tercer trimestre de 2016. http://www.inegi.org.mx/saladeprensa/boletines/2016/pib_pconst/pib_pconst2016_11.pdf

  • Johansen S (1988) Statistical analysis of cointegration vectors. J Econ Dyn Control 12(1):231–254

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansen S (1991) Estimation and hypothesis testing of cointegrating vectors in Gaussian vector autoregressive models. Econometrica 59(1):1551–1580

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kapetanios G (2010) A testing procedure for determining the number of factors in approximate factor models with large datasets. J Bus Econ Stat 28(3):397–409

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kehoe T, Ruhl K (2010) Why have economic reforms in Mexico not generated growth? J Econ Lit 48(4):1005–1017

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kunst R, Neusser K (1997) Cointegration in a macroeconomic system. J Appl Econ 5(1):351–365

    Google Scholar 

  • Lahiri K, Monokroussos G, Yongchen Z (2016) Forecasting consumption: the role of consumer confidence in real time with many predictors. J Appl Econ 31(7):1254–1275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lütkepohl H (2006) New introduction to multiple time series analysis. Springer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Marcellino M, Stock JH, Watson MW (2003) Macroeconomic forecasting in the euro area: country specific versus euro wide information. Eur Econ Rev 47(1):1–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Onatski A (2010) Determining the number of factors from empirical distribution of eigenvalues. Rev Econ Stat 92(4):1004–1016

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Panopoulou E, Vrontos S (2015) Hedge fund return predictability: to combine forecast or combine information? J Bank Financ 56:103–122

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peña D, Poncela P (2004) Forecasting with nonstationary dynamic factor models. J Econom 119(1):291–321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reijer AHJ (2005) Forecasting Dutch GDP using large scale factor models. Netherlands Central Bank Working Paper

  • Rodriguez-Pose A, Villarreal E (2015) Innovation and regional growth in Mexico: 2000–2010. Growth Change 46(2):172–195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sargent TJ, Sims CA (1977) Business cycle modeling without pretending to have too much a priory economic theory. In: Sims CA (ed) New methods in business cycle research. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Minneapolis

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumacher C (2007) Forecasting German GDP using alternative factor models based on large datasets. J Forecast 26(4):1167–1179

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwellnus C (2011) Macroeconomic and structural policies to further stabilise the Mexican economy. OECD Economics Department Working Papers 906

  • Stock JH, Watson MW (1988) Testing for common trends. J Am Stat Assoc 83(1):1097–1107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock JH, Watson MW (2002a) Forecasting using principal components from a large number of predictors. J Am Stat Assoc 97(1):1169–1179

    Google Scholar 

  • Stock JH, Watson MW (2002b) Macroeconomic forecasting using diffusion indexes. J Bus Econ Stat 20(1):147–163

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock JH, Watson MW (2005) Implications of dynamic factor models for VAR analysis. NBER Working Paper 11467

  • Stock JH, Watson MW (2011) Dynamic factor models. In: Clements MP, Hendry DF (eds) Oxford handbook of economic forecasting. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Vahid F, Engle RF (1993) Common trends and common cycles. J Appl Econom 8(1):341–360

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilms I, Croux C (2016) Forecasting using sparse cointegration. Int J Forecast 32(4):1256–1267

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2016a) Mexico overview. World Bank, Washington, DC. http://www.worldbank.org/en/country/mexico/overview#3

  • World Bank (2016b) World development indicators. World Bank, Washington, DC. http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators

Download references

Acknowledgements

Partial financial support from the CONACYT CB-2015-01-252996 is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Francisco Corona.

Annex: Variables in the dynamic factor model

Annex: Variables in the dynamic factor model

\(\#\)

Short

Long

Block

Log

SA

T

1

EXP TOT

Total absolute value exports

Balance of trade

Yes

Yes

1

2

EXP PET TOT

Oil exports

Balance of trade

Yes

Yes

1

3

EXP PET CRU

Crude oil exports

Balance of trade

Yes

Yes

1

4

EXP PET OTR

Other oil exports

Balance of trade

Yes

Yes

1

5

EXP NO PET

Non-oil exports

Balance of trade

Yes

Yes

1

6

EXP NO PET AGR

Farming exports

Balance of trade

Yes

Yes

1

7

EXP NO PET EXTRAC

Extractive exports

Balance of trade

Yes

Yes

1

8

EXP MAN AUT

Automotive exports

Balance of trade

Yes

Yes

1

9

EXP NO MAN RES

Manufacture exports

Balance of trade

Yes

Yes

1

10

IMP TOT PET

Total oil imports

Balance of trade

Yes

Yes

1

11

IMP CON TOT

Consumption goods imports

Balance of trade

Yes

Yes

1

12

IMP CON PET

Consumption goods oil imports

Balance of trade

Yes

No

1

13

IMP CON NO PET

Consumption goods non-oil imports

Balance of trade

Yes

Yes

1

14

IMP INT PET

Intermediate goods oil imports

Balance of trade

Yes

Yes

1

15

IMP BK

Capital goods imports

Balance of trade

Yes

Yes

1

16

REM TOT

Total remittances

Balance of trade

Yes

Yes

1

17

REM MO

Money orders remittances

Balance of trade

Yes

Yes

1

18

REM TRANS ELECT

Electronic transfers remittances

Balance of trade

Yes

Yes

1

19

REM EFEC

Cash and in-kind remittances

Balance of trade

Yes

Yes

1

20

I CONF

Consumer confidence index

Consumer confidence

Yes

Yes

1

21

I CONF COMP HOG 12

Index: compared to this household’s economic situation 12 months ago, how do you think your situation is at the moment?

Consumer confidence

Yes

Yes

1

22

I CONF FUT COMP PAI 12

Index: how do you foresee this household’s economic situation in 12 months’ time, compared to the current situation?

Consumer confidence

Yes

Yes

2

23

I CONF COMP PAI 12

Index: how do you consider the country’s economic situation today compared to 12 months ago?

Consumer confidence

Yes

Yes

1

24

I CONF FUT COMP PAI 12

Index: how do you foresee the country’s economic situation in 12 months’ time?

Consumer confidence

Yes

Yes

1

25

I CONF POS FUT

Index: comparing the current economic situation with that of a year ago, how do you consider at the present moment the possibilities that you or any of the members of this household

Consumer confidence

Yes

Yes

1

26

I CONF B

Consumer confidence index (balance)

Consumer confidence

Yes

Yes

2

27

COMP 12 B

Other complementary index: how would you describe your economic situation compared to 12 months ago?

Consumer confidence

Yes

Yes

1

28

FUT 12 B

Other complementary index: and how do you think your economic situation will be in 12 months, compared to the current situation?

Consumer confidence

Yes

Yes

1

29

POSI 12

Other complementary index: at this moment, are you more able to buy clothes, shoes, food, etc., than a year ago?

Consumer confidence

Yes

Yes

1

30

POSI 12 VAC

Other complementary index: do you consider that during the next 12 months you or any of the members of this household will afford to go on vacation?

Consumer confidence

Yes

Yes

1

31

POS AHO

Other complementary index: are you currently able to save some of your income?

Consumer confidence

Yes

Yes

1

32

COMP C 12

Other complementary index: how do you foresee your economic conditions to save in 12 months’ time compared to current conditions?

Consumer confidence

Yes

Yes

1

33

COMP PRE

Other complementary index: compared with the previous 12 months, how do you think prices will behave in the country in the next 12 months?

Consumer confidence

Yes

Yes

1

34

COMP 12 EMP

Other complementary index: do you think that employment in the country in the next 12 months is going to increase, remain the same, or decrease?

Consumer confidence

Yes

Yes

1

35

AUT 12

Other supplemental index: are any members of this household or you planning to buy a new or used car in the next 2 years?

Consumer confidence

Yes

Yes

1

36

PLA AUT 2

Other complementary index: are any members of this household or you planning to buy, build or remodel a home in the next 2 years?

Consumer confidence

Yes

Yes

1

37

PLA CONST 2

Other complementary index: (balance) compared with the previous 12 months, how do you think prices will behave in the country in the next 12 months?

Consumer confidence

Yes

Yes

1

38

IVF

Physical volume index total

Consumption

Yes

Yes

2

39

IVFBST

IVF goods and services of national origin total

Consumption

Yes

Yes

2

40

IVFB

IVF goods and services of national origin goods

Consumption

Yes

Yes

1

41

IVFS

IVF goods and services of national origin services

Consumption

Yes

Yes

2

42

IVFBI

IVF imported goods

Consumption

Yes

Yes

1

43

IVFAT

IVF total accumulative

Consumption

Yes

Yes

1

44

IVFNB

IVFAT goods and services of national origin goods

Consumption

Yes

Yes

1

45

IVFNS

IVFAT goods and services of national origin services

Consumption

Yes

Yes

2

46

IVFBIMP

IVFAT imported goods

Consumption

Yes

Yes

1

47

IGAE A 1

IGAE primary activities

Economic activity

Yes

Yes

1

48

IGAE A 2

IGAE secondary activities total

Economic activity

Yes

Yes

1

49

IGAE A 21

IGAE secondary activities 21 mining

Economic activity

Yes

Yes

1

50

IGAE A 22

IGAE secondary activities 22

Economic activity

Yes

Yes

1

51

IGAE A 31–33

IGAE secondary activities 31–33

Economic activity

Yes

Yes

1

52

IGAE A 3

IGAE tertiary activities total

Economic activity

Yes

Yes

1

53

IGAE A 43–46

IGAE tertiary activities 43–46 trade

Economic activity

Yes

Yes

1

54

IGAE A 48 49 51

IGAE tertiary activities 48–49–51. Transport, mail, and storage; mass media information

Economic activity

Yes

Yes

2

55

IGAE A 52–53

IGAE tertiary activities 52–53 financial and insurance services; real estate and rental services of movable and intangible goods

Economic activity

Yes

Yes

1

56

IGAE A 54–56

IGAE tertiary activities 54–55–56 professional, scientific and technical services; corporate; business support services and waste management and remediation services

Economic activity

Yes

Yes

2

57

IGAE A 61–62

IGAE tertiary activities 61–62 educational services; health and social work services

Economic activity

Yes

Yes

1

58

IGAE A 71–81

IGAE tertiary activities 71–81 cultural and sporting recreation services, and other recreational services; other services except government activities

Economic activity

Yes

Yes

2

59

IGAE 72

IGAE tertiary activities 72 temporary accommodation and food and beverage preparation services

Economic activity

Yes

Yes

1

60

PEO

Economically active population: occupied population

Employment

Yes

Yes

1

61

PED

Economically active population: unemployed population

Employment

Yes

Yes

1

62

PO S AGR

Occupied population by agriculture economic activity sector

Employment

Yes

Yes

1

63

PO CONS

Occupied population by construction economic activity sector

Employment

Yes

Yes

1

64

PO MAN

Occupied population by manufacturing industry economic activity sector

Employment

Yes

Yes

1

65

TIIE

Interbank interest rates, bank collection costs, and CETES performance Interbank interest rate (TIIE)

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

66

CETES

Interbank interest rates, bank funding costs, and CETES performance cost of time deposits of liabilities denominated in US dollars (CCP-dollars)

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

67

TC

Exchange rate of peso against dollar and UDIS value Interbank (sale)

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

68

I TC R

Mexican peso real exchange rate index

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

69

I TC R VAR

Mexican peso real exchange rate index annual change

Financial

No

No

1

70

IPCBMV

Index of prices and quotes of the Mexican stock exchange maximum

Financial

Yes

No

1

71

TIIL

International interest rates: Libor rate

Financial

Yes

No

1

72

M1

M1 money and coins held by the public

Financial

Yes

Yes

2

73

M1 CB

M1 foreign currency checking accounts at resident banks

Financial

Yes

Yes

2

74

M1 DAP

M1 demand deposits of savings and loan companies

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

75

M2 CIRT

Internal funding of resident banks total

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

76

M2 CIBR

Domestic funding from resident banks

Financial

Yes

No

1

77

M2 CIBR ME

Internal collection of resident banks in foreign currency

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

78

M2 VP GF

Securities issued by the Federal Government total

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

79

IPAB

IPAB total

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

80

IPAB S

IPAB securities held by the siefores

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

81

IPAB EPP

IPAB securities held by public and private companies

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

82

M2 SIEFORES

Other public securities held by the siefores

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

83

M2 EPP

Other public securities owned by public and private companies

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

84

M2 V P T

Private securities total

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

85

M2 V P SIEFORES

Private securities held by the siefores

Financial

Yes

No

1

86

M2 V P EPP

Private securities owned by public and private companies

Financial

Yes

Yes

2

87

FON F SIEFORES

Savings funds for withdrawal from SIEFORES total

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

88

FON F SIEFORES BM

Retirement funds at the Banco de Mexico total

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

89

SIEFORES

Retirement funds at the Banco de Mexico total

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

90

M3

Domestic financial assets held by non-residents total

Financial

Yes

No

2

91

M3 BRT

Collection of resident banks total

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

92

M3 BRMN

Collection of resident banks in national currency

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

93

M3 BRME

Collection of resident banks in foreign currency

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

94

M3 VP T

Government securities held by non-residents total

Financial

Yes

No

2

95

M3 GF

Securities issued by the Federal Government total

Financial

Yes

Yes

2

96

M3 IPAB

Public securities held by non-residents securities issued by the IPAB

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

97

M4

Acquisition of branches and agencies of Mexican banks abroad total

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

98

M4 DR

Deposits of residents total

Financial

Yes

Yes

1

99

M4 DNR

Deposits of non-residents total

Financial

Yes

No

1

100

IVFI 212

Mining of metallic and non-metallic minerals, except oil and gas

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

101

IVFI 213

Mining-related services

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

102

IVFI 23

Construction total

Industrial

Yes

Yes

2

103

IVFI 237

Construction of civil engineering works

Industrial

Yes

Yes

2

104

IVFI 238

Specialized construction works

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

105

IVFI 311

Manufacturing 311 industry

Industrial

Yes

Yes

2

106

IVFI 312

Manufacturing 312 beverages and tobacco industry

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

107

IVFI 313

Manufacturing 313 manufacture of textiles and textile finishing

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

108

IVFI 314

Manufacturing 314 manufacture of textiles, except apparel

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

109

IVFI 315

Manufacturing 315 manufacture of clothing

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

110

IVFI 316

Manufacturing 316 tanning and finishing of leather, manufacture of leather and leather substitutes materials

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

111

IVFI 321

Manufacturing 321 wood industry

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

112

IVFI 322

Manufacturing 322 paper industry

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

113

IVFI 323

Manufacturing 323 printing and related industries

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

114

IVFI 324

Manufacturing 324 manufacture of petroleum products and coal

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

115

IVFI 325

Manufacturing industries 325 chemical industry

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

116

IVFI 326

Manufacturing 326 Plastic and rubber industry

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

117

IVFI 327

Manufacturing 327 manufacture of non-metallic mineral products

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

118

IVFI 331

Manufacturing industries 331 basic metal industries

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

119

IVFI 332

Manufacturing 332 manufacture of metal products

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

120

IVFI 333

Manufacturing 333 manufacture of machinery and equipment

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

121

IVFI 334

Manufacturing 334 manufacture of computer equipment, communication, measurement and other electronic equipment, components and accessories

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

122

IVFI 335

Manufacturing 335 manufacture of electrical fittings, electrical apparatus, and electric power generation equipment

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

123

IVFI 336

Manufacturing 336 manufacture of transport equipment

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

124

IVFI 337

Manufacturing 337 manufacture of furniture, mattresses, and blinds

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

125

IVFI 339

Manufacturing 339 other industrial manufacturing

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

126

IVFIA

Accumulated total of industrial activity

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

127

IVFIA 21

Accumulated mining total mining

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

128

IVFIA 212

Accumulated mining of metallic and non-metallic minerals, other than oil and gas

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

129

IVFIA 213

Accumulated mining-related services

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

130

IVFIA 22

Accumulated total generation, transmission and distribution of electricity, water and gas supply by pipelines to the final consumer

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

131

IVFIA 222

Accumulated Water supply and piped gas supply to the final consumer

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

132

IVFIA 23

Accumulated construction total

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

133

IVFIA 236

Accumulated building

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

134

IVFIA 237

Accumulated construction of civil engineering works

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

135

IVFIA 238

Accumulated specialized construction work

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

136

IVFIA 31–33

Accumulated manufacturing industry total

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

137

IVFIA 311

Accumulated 311 food industry

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

138

IVFIA 312

Accumulated 312 beverages and tobacco industry

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

139

IVFIA 313

Accumulated manufacturing industry 313

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

140

IVFIA 314

Accumulated manufacturing industry 314

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

141

IVFIA 315

Accumulated manufacturing industry 315

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

142

IVFIA 316

Accumulated manufacturing industry 316 tanning and finishing of leather

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

143

IVFIA 321

Accumulated manufacturing industry 321

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

144

IVFIA 322

Accumulated manufacturing 322 Paper industry

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

145

IVFIA 323

Accumulated manufacturing 323 printing and related industries

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

146

IVFIA 324

Accumulated manufacturing 324 manufacture of petroleum products and coal

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

147

IVFIA 325

Accumulated manufacturing industries 325 chemical industry

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

148

IVFIA 326

Accumulated manufacturing 326 plastic and rubber industry

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

149

IVFIA 327

Accumulated manufacturing 327 manufacture of non-metallic mineral products

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

150

IVFIA 331

Accumulated manufacturing 331 basic metal industries

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

151

IVFIA 332

Accumulated manufacturing 332 manufacture of metal products

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

152

IVFIA 333

Accumulated manufacturing 333 manufacture of machinery and equipment

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

153

IVFIA 334

Accumulated manufacturing 334 manufacture of computer, communication, measurement and other electronic equipment, components, and accessories

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

154

IVFIA 335

Accumulated manufacturing 335 manufacture of accessories, electrical apparatus, and electric power generation equipment

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

155

IVFIA 336

Accumulated manufacturing 336 manufacture of transport equipment

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

156

IVFIA 337

Accumulated manufacturing 337 manufacture of furniture, mattresses, and blinds

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

157

IVFIA 339

Accumulated manufacturing 339 other manufacturing

Industrial

Yes

Yes

1

158

IPI EUA

Indices of United States industrial production

International

Yes

Yes

1

159

TD EUA

United States unemployment rates

International

Yes

No

2

160

OM EUA

United States monetary offer

International

Yes

No

2

161

TI 3M

Interest rate USA 3 months

International

Yes

Yes

1

162

TI 6M

Interest rate USA 6 months

International

Yes

Yes

1

163

TI 1M

Interest rate USA 1 year

International

No

Yes

2

164

TI 2A

Interest rate USA 2 years

International

Yes

No

1

165

TI 3A

Interest rate USA 3 years

International

Yes

No

1

166

TI 5A

Interest rate USA 5 years

International

Yes

No

1

167

TI 10A

Interest rate USA 10 years

International

Yes

No

1

168

TI 20

Interest rate USA 20 years

International

Yes

No

1

169

TI FF

Interest rate USA federal funds

International

Yes

No

1

170

I REMUN EUA

Manufacturing remunerations USA

International

Yes

Yes

2

171

RESER EUA

Total reserves (not including gold) USA

International

Yes

No

1

172

EXP EUA

Total exports USA

International

Yes

No

1

173

IMP EUA

Total imports USA

International

Yes

No

1

174

BC EUA

Balance of trade USA

International

No

No

1

175

INV T

Investment total

Investment

Yes

Yes

1

176

INV CON

Investment residential

Investment

Yes

Yes

2

177

INV CON NR

Investment non-residential

Investment

Yes

Yes

2

178

INV MET

Investment total machines and equipment

Investment

Yes

Yes

1

179

INV ME

Investment machines and equipment

Investment

Yes

Yes

1

180

INV MEO

Investment machines, equipment, and others

Investment

Yes

Yes

1

181

INV MET

Investment transporting equipment (imported)

Investment

Yes

Yes

1

182

INV MAEO

Investment machines, equipment and others (imported)

Investment

Yes

Yes

1

183

TUR VS

Total balance

Miscellaneous

Yes

Yes

1

184

TUR IT

Total income

Miscellaneous

Yes

Yes

1

185

TUR TI

International tourists

Miscellaneous

Yes

Yes

1

186

TUR ET

Total expenditure

Miscellaneous

Yes

Yes

1

187

TUR TIT

Total expenditure (international tourists)

Miscellaneous

Yes

Yes

1

188

TUR VIT

Total income (volume)

Miscellaneous

Yes

Yes

1

189

TUR ITIT

Total income (international tourists)

Miscellaneous

Yes

Yes

1

190

TUR ET V

Total expenditure (volume)

Miscellaneous

Yes

Yes

1

191

TUR ET TUT

Total expenditure (international tourists)

Miscellaneous

Yes

Yes

1

192

TUR GM IT

Expenditure average (income total)

Miscellaneous

Yes

Yes

1

193

TUR GM I TUT

Expenditure average international tourists (income total)

Miscellaneous

Yes

Yes

1

194

TUR GM ET

Expenditure average (expenditure total)

Miscellaneous

Yes

Yes

1

195

TUR GM E TIT

Expenditure average international tourists (expenditure total)

Miscellaneous

Yes

Yes

1

196

AUT

Production total automotive

Miscellaneous

Yes

Yes

1

197

AUT CAM T

Sales to the public. Total automotive

Miscellaneous

Yes

Yes

1

198

AUT CAM TT

Sales to the public. Total buses

Miscellaneous

Yes

Yes

1

199

AUT CAM TN

Sales to the public. Total buses (national)

Miscellaneous

Yes

Yes

1

200

AUT CAM TI

Sales to the public. Total buses (imported)

Miscellaneous

Yes

Yes

2

201

INPC

National index of consumer prices

Prices

Yes

Yes

1

202

INPC 4

INPC clothing, footwear, and accessories

Prices

Yes

Yes

2

203

INPC 5

INPC furniture, household appliances, and accessories

Prices

Yes

Yes

2

204

INPC 5

INPC health and personal care

Prices

Yes

Yes

2

205

INPC 6

INPC transportation

Prices

Yes

Yes

2

206

INPC S

INPC underlying

Prices

Yes

Yes

2

207

INPC SM

INPC underlying goods

Prices

Yes

Yes

2

208

INPP 21

National index of producer prices (INPP) mining without oil

Prices

Yes

No

1

209

INPP 22

INPP generation, transmission and distribution of electricity, water and gas supply by pipelines to the final consumer

Prices

Yes

Yes

1

210

INPP 23

INPP construction

Prices

Yes

No

1

211

INPP 48-49

INPP transportation, post and storage

Prices

Yes

Yes

2

  1. Log denotes logarithmic transformation, SA means seasonal adjustment, and T if 1 denotes that \(y_t \sim I(1)\) and 2 that \(\varDelta y_t \sim I(1)\)

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Corona, F., González-Farías, G. & Orraca, P. A dynamic factor model for the Mexican economy: are common trends useful when predicting economic activity?. Lat Am Econ Rev 26, 7 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40503-017-0044-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40503-017-0044-7

Keywords

JEL Classification